|
||||||
|
Oil
A dangerous addiction
Dec 13th 2001
From The Economist print edition
|
|
|
|
|
The world is increasingly dependent on Middle Eastern oil. After
September 11th, this could be cause for increased alarm—or just common sense
HOW
much is a barrel of oil worth? In the Middle East, reserves can cost barely a
dollar to lift out of the ground. Add a decent profit margin, and you still
have an exceedingly modest price. Yet quite a bit of the world's oil comes from
far more expensive places. Last year, the price averaged $27 a barrel.
It
is not geology that determines the oil price, however, still less the free
interplay of supply and demand. Mostly, it is the whims of the Organisation of
Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), the ill-disciplined cartel led by Saudi Arabia.
Small wonder, then, that the price of oil has yo-yoed in the past three years.
Prices have recently plunged to below $17 a barrel as an anaemic world economy
and a stand-off between OPEC and Russia, the biggest non-cartel exporter,
pushed the oil market to the brink of short-term collapse.
Only
Osama bin Laden, it seems, can give you a fixed price for a barrel of oil. He
makes it $144. Several years ago, the leader of the al-Qaeda terrorists issued
a little-noticed proclamation on energy economics. In it, he accused the United
States of “the biggest theft in history” for using its military presence in
Saudi Arabia to keep oil prices down. In his view, that larceny adds up to $36
trillion. America, he insisted, now owes each Muslim in the world around
$30,000, and still counting.
After
September 11th, energy-security experts have Mr bin Laden, his sympathisers and
terrorists in general very much in mind. America used to assume that, if a
hostile group or regime took over the Middle Eastern oilfields, it would send
in its troops to quash the troublemakers and protect the oil. Now those
terrorists may have nuclear weapons that they could turn either against America
or against the oilfields themselves.
Yet
the real cause for worry, a related one, is much longer-term. Because the world
remains so dependent on oil for transport, it cannot stand any disruption in
supplies. And there is a strong possibility of such a supply-shock at some time
in the next few decades. How will the United States cope with this?
In too few hands
|
|
|
|
|
Oil
is not scarce. Enough lies underground to keep the world's motors humming for
several decades yet. The snag is that the lion's share of it—and almost all the
oil that is cheap to extract—lies under the desert sands of a handful of
countries around the Persian Gulf (see map).
Today,
Saudi Arabia alone sits on a quarter of the world's proven oil reserves, and
four of its neighbours can boast about a tenth each. Because the Saudis choose
not to produce as much oil as they could, OPEC's share
of world oil exports is only about 40%: influential, but not enough to control
prices completely. As the world continues to deplete non-OPEC oil,
however, that share will increase dramatically—and with it, the market power of
those Middle Eastern regimes. All the more likely, then, that supplies may be
disrupted. This threat is particularly acute for the United States, which is
both the biggest oil-guzzler and the de facto guarantor of oil supplies for its
allies.
The
Saudis, unsurprisingly, deny that a shock is in prospect at all. Oil is “a
global market,” said Ali al-Naimi, the oil minister, two years ago. “Those who
propagate the issue of supply insecurity, dangers of import dependence and
perceived instability of the Arabian Gulf are ignoring realities.” He pointed
out that his country intentionally maintains a cushion of excess capacity
against any disruption of supply. It was his country's buffer, not any non-OPEC production,
he noted, that came to the rescue during the Iranian revolution, the Iran-Iraq
war and the Gulf war.
All
this is true, but what if the Saudi regime were overthrown by some rabidly
anti-western band? Not to worry, argues John Browne, chairman of BP:
“However fundamentalist, a regime still needs money to look after its people.”
His sentiment is echoed by many economists, who insist that oil is a “fungible”
commodity that is worthless unless it gets to market. In the long term, that is
doubtless true. But even short-term disruptions can wreak havoc on the world
economy: when the Iranian revolutionaries booted out the shah, Iran's oil
exports collapsed. And some future revolutionaries may choose to forgo oil
revenues and live in poverty to punish the West.
Donald
Losman, in a provocative paper published by the Cato Institute, a libertarian
think-tank, goes further. He argues, with some justification, that the pain
associated with previous oil shocks had more to do with foolish policy
responses by western governments meddling in the market than with disruptions
to supply. He calculates that America wastes $30 billion-60 billion a year
safeguarding Middle Eastern oil supplies even though its imports from that
region totalled only about $10 billion a year during the 1990s. He also
observes that semiconductors, the backbone of the digital economy, come mostly
from one place (Taiwan), but American soldiers do not guard chip plants.
Oil's uniqueness
Yet
semiconductors and oil are not at all the same. The American economy could
manage without new semiconductors for some time, but it would grind to a
painful halt the moment oil dried up. Semiconductor plants can also be built
anywhere, but oil is found only in certain spots. The petrol riots in Britain
in the autumn of 2000 showed how easily a modern economy can be brought to its
knees when its oil supplies are disrupted.
If
oil is essential, then, why not simply boost non-OPEC supplies?
President Bush, extolling America's “energy independence”, has been trying to
push a bill through Congress that would open part of the Arctic National
Wildlife Refuge in Alaska to oil-drilling. But America consumes so much that
all the oil in Alaska would not dent its reliance on the imported stuff.
The
dramatic wave of non-OPEC discoveries in the 1960s and
1970s in the North Sea, Alaska and other places has helped to counterbalance OPEC's
pricing power. But these big fields are about to enter a phase of rapid
decline. Part of the explanation is simple old age. In the North Sea, for
example, most large fields are now 70-90% depleted. And the dramatic techniques
that have allowed big oil companies to improve oil-recovery rates have ended up
draining fields all the faster.
Harry
Longwell, a top manager at ExxonMobil, insists that a new wave of non-OPEC
development, from the Caspian to the deep waters of the Gulf of Mexico, is
technically feasible. However, he says that it will require “huge new
investments”. How much? The International Energy Agency reckons big oil firms
will have to invest a whopping $1 trillion upstream over the next decade.
Developing non-conventional hydrocarbons, such as Canada's tar sands, would
prove even more expensive. Such stuff would also take much longer to bring to
market, and so prove less valuable as a buffer stock. In other words, the real
concern is not the scarcity of hydrocarbons, but the ever-higher cost and
commercial risk of finding non-OPEC reserves—especially since price volatility
discourages investment.
|
|
|
|
|
Now
here's the rub: even accepting in full the oil industry's optimistic assessment
that it can meet this challenge, the “call on OPEC” will
still increase dramatically over the next 20 years (see chart). In order to
meet the world's unchecked thirst for oil, forecasters are assuming (perhaps
praying is a better word) that Saudi Arabia and its neighbours will invest the
vast sums needed to expand output. If they do not, it will be the world's
consumers who will pay the price.
Saving and conserving
What
can be done? Unfortunately, petroleum has a near-monopoly grip on transport.
The best thing governments can do is to buy some insurance against politically
inspired supply disruptions, and the panics and hoarding that go with them, by
greatly expanding buffer stocks of oil.
This
is all the more urgent because structural changes in the oil industry
(mega-mergers, cost-cutting and a move to just-in-time inventories) mean that
privately held reserves have fallen steeply from their levels in the 1970s. Add
to this the official neglect of government stockpiles, and you get a world that
is needlessly vulnerable to the next oil shock.
Mr
Bush has now begun to rebuild America's Strategic Petroleum Reserve.
Conservation, too, after years of sneers, is firmly on the American political
agenda. Yet even conservation has drawbacks: it may simply mean less mobility
and less trade. The better way forward is to promote energy efficiency. The
United States now imports about 11m barrels of oil per day (bpd), around a
seventh of the world's total production. Philip Verleger, an energy economist,
reckons that the figure would be only 5m or 6m bpd if America had made a
serious effort to improve fuel efficiency after the previous shocks.
One
efficiency measure under debate is the strengthening of the Corporate Average
Fuel Economy (CAFE) laws: raising them for cars, and closing the
loophole that allows light trucks and sport-utility vehicles to use more
petrol. A study done by America's National Academy of Sciences (NAS)
earlier this year was certain that, with technologies that are readily
available, reductions in fuel use of up to 20% could be achieved comfortably.
Some vehicles could achieve a 50% increase in fuel economy—and more if radical
new technologies, such as fuel cells, take off.
Against shocks, taxes
However,
a world powered largely by fuel cells (which combine hydrogen and oxygen to
produce electricity) could be decades away, especially if all America does is
tinker with fuel-efficiency standards. The best way to encourage the
development of new transport fuels and technologies is through taxation that
reflects the “energy security” risk (as well as dangers to health and the
environment) of burning oil. Europe recognises this, and over the past decade
has started to shift the burden of taxation from income to, for example, carbon
emissions.
What
are the chances that America too will start to tackle its petro-addiction?
James Schlesinger, a former energy secretary, says he still bears the bruises
from attempting to propose higher oil taxes in the past. A recent encounter on
Capitol Hill suggests that times have not changed much. After the NAS panel
had prepared a preliminary report, Paul Portney, its chairman, was asked to
address a congressional panel. George Allen, a senator from Virginia, was
plainly unhappy with the report's suggestion that fossil-fuel use could be
easily curbed by tightening CAFE regulations. The visitor was asked whether there
was any other way to encourage fuel efficiency without resorting to
market-distorting regulations.
Why,
yes, said Mr Portney: you could make a significant increase in the federal
petrol tax. Mr Allen was astounded. The notion, he said, was “just flat
ignorant”. Senator John Kerry, the panel's chairman, retorted in frustration,
“I can see the headlines tomorrow: ‘Virginia senator calls Europeans ignorant',
or maybe worse.” Mr Allen was unrepentant. The road away from dependence on OPEC and
Middle Eastern oil could be long indeed.
|
|
Copyright
© 2002 The Economist Newspaper and The Economist Group. All rights reserved. |
|
|