An
Inquiry into the Nature and
Causes of the Wealth of Nations
by Adam Smith, 1776
Book 1, Chapter 9
OF THE PROFITS OF STOCK
[I, ix, 1, p. 105]
THE rise and fall in the profits of stock depend upon the same causes with
the rise and fall in the wages of labour, the increasing or declining
state of the wealth of the society; but those causes affect the one and
the other very differently.
The increase of stock, which raises wages, tends to lower profit. When the
stocks of many rich merchants are turned into the same trade, their mutual
competition naturally tends to lower its profit; and when there is a like
increase of stock in all the different trades carried on in the same
society, the same competition must produce the same effect in them all.
It is not easy, it has already been observed, to ascertain what are the
average wages of labour even in a particular place, and at a particular
time. . . But even this can seldom be done with regard to the profits of
stock. Profit is so very fluctuating that the person who carries on a
particular trade cannot always tell you himself what is the average of his
annual profit. . .
But though it may be impossible to determine, with any
degree of precision, what are or were the average profits of stock, either
in the present or in ancient times, some notion may be formed of them from
the interest of money. It may be laid down as a maxim, that wherever a
great deal can be made by the use of money, a great deal will commonly be
given for the use of it… According, therefore, as the usual market rate of
interest varies in any country, we may be assured that the ordinary
profits of stock must vary with it, must sink as it sinks, and rise as it
rises. The progress of interest, therefore, may lead us to form some
notion of the progress of profit.
U.S. Profits and Interest, 1950-2001
By the 37th of Henry VIII all
interest above ten per cent was declared unlawful. More, it seems, had
sometimes been taken before that. In the reign of Edward VI religious zeal
prohibited all interest. This prohibition, however, like all others of the
same kind, is said to have produced no effect, and probably rather
increased than diminished the evil of usury. The statute of Henry VIII was
revived by the 13th of Elizabeth, c. 8, and ten per cent continued to be
the legal rate of interest till the 21st of James I, when it was
restricted to eight per cent. It was reduced to six per cent soon after
the Restoration, and by the 12th of Queen Anne to five per cent. All these
different statutory regulations seem to have been made with great
propriety. They seem to have followed and not to have gone before the
market rate of interest, or the rate at which people of good credit
usually borrowed. Since the time of Queen Anne, five per cent seems to
have been rather above than below the market rate. Before the late war,
the government borrowed at three per cent; and people of good credit in
the capital, and in many other parts of the kingdom, at three and a half,
four, and four and a half per cent.
Since the time of Henry VIII the wealth and revenue of the country have
been continually advancing, and, in the course of their progress, their
pace seems rather to have been gradually accelerated than retarded. They
seem not only to have been going on, but to have been going on faster and
faster. The wages of labour have been continually increasing during the
same period, and in the greater part of the different branches of trade
and manufactures the profits of stock have been diminishing.
[I, ix, 18, p. 113]
The lowest ordinary rate of profit must always be something more than what
is sufficient to compensate the occasional losses to which every
employment of stock is exposed. It is this surplus only which is neat or
clear profit. What is called gross profit comprehends frequently, not only
this surplus, but what is retained for compensating such extraordinary
losses. The interest which the borrower can afford to pay is in proportion
to the clear profit only.
[I, ix, 21, p. 113]
The highest ordinary rate of profit may be such as, in the price of the
greater part of commodities, eats up the whole of what should go to the
rent of the land, and leaves only what is sufficient to pay the labour of
preparing and bringing them to market, according to the lowest rate at
which labour can anywhere be paid, the bare subsistence of the labourer.
The workman must always have been fed in some way or other while he was
about the work; but the landlord may not always have been paid. The
profits of the trade which the servants of the East India Company carry on
in Bengal may not perhaps be very far from this rate.
[I, ix, 24, p. 115]
Our merchants and master-manufacturers
complain much of the bad effects of high wages in raising the price, and
thereby lessening the sale of their goods both at home and abroad. They
say nothing concerning the bad effects of high profits. They are silent
with regard to the pernicious effects of their own gains. They complain
only of those of other people.
Book 1, Chapter 10
OF WAGES AND PROFIT IN THE DIFFERENT
EMPLOYMENTS OF LABOUR AND STOCK
[I, x, Part 2, 36, p. 127]
In all the different employments of stock, the ordinary rate of profit
varies more or less with the certainty or uncertainty of the returns.
These are in general less uncertain in the inland than in the foreign
trade, and in some branches of foreign trade than in others; in the trade
to North America, for example, than in that to Jamaica. The ordinary rate
of profit always rises more or less with the risk.
[I, x, Part 3, 22, p. 142]
That the industry which is carried on in towns is, everywhere in Europe,
more advantageous than that which is carried on in the country, without
entering into any very nice computations, we may satisfy ourselves by one
very simple and obvious observation. In every country of Europe we find,
at least, a hundred people who have acquired great fortunes from small
beginnings by trade and manufactures, the industry which properly belongs
to towns, for one who has done so by that which properly belongs to the
country, the raising of rude produce by the improvement and cultivation of
land…
The inhabitants of a
town, being collected into one place, can easily combine together. The
most insignificant trades carried on in towns have accordingly, in some
place or other, been incorporated, and even where they have never been
incorporated, yet the corporation spirit, the jealousy of strangers, the
aversion to take apprentices, or to communicate the secret of their trade,
generally prevail in them, and often teach them, by voluntary associations
and agreements, to prevent that free competition which they cannot
prohibit by by laws. . .
[I, x, Part 3, 23, p. 143]
The inhabitants of the country, dispersed in distant places, cannot easily
combine together. They have not only never been incorporated, but the
corporation spirit never has prevailed among them. No apprenticeship has
ever been thought necessary to qualify for husbandry, the great trade of
the country.
[I, x, Part 3, 27, p. 145]
People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and
diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public,
or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent
such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would be
consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder
people of the same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to
do nothing to facilitate such assemblies, much less to render them
necessary.
A regulation which
obliges all those of the same trade in a particular town to enter their
names and places of abode in a public register, facilitates such
assemblies. It connects individuals who might never otherwise be known to
one another, and gives every man of the trade a direction where to find
every other man of it…
[I, x, Part 3, 46, p. 152]
The obstruction which corporation laws give to the free circulation of
labour is common, I believe, to every part of Europe. That which is given
to it by the Poor Laws is, so far as I know, peculiar to England. It
consists in the difficulty which a poor man finds in obtaining a
settlement, or even in being allowed to exercise his industry in any
parish but that to which he belongs…
When by the destruction of monasteries the poor had been deprived of the
charity of those religious houses, after some other ineffectual attempts
for their relief, it was enacted by the 43rd of Elizabeth, c. 2 [in 1601],
that every parish should be bound to provide for its own poor…
By this statute the necessity of providing for their own poor was
indispensably imposed upon every parish. Who were to be considered as the
poor of each parish became, therefore, a question of some importance. This
question, after some variation, was at last determined by the 13th and
14th of Charles II when it was enacted, that forty days' undisturbed
residence should gain any person a settlement in any parish; but that
within that time it should be lawful for two justices of the peace, upon
complaint made by the churchwardens or overseers of the poor, to remove
any new inhabitant to the parish where he was last legally settled; unless
he either rented a tenement of ten pounds a year, or could give such
security for the discharge of the parish where he was then living, as
those justices should judge sufficient.
Some frauds, it is said, were committed in consequence of this statute;
parish officers sometimes bribing their own poor to go clandestinely to
another parish…
Book 1, Chapter 11
OF THE RENT OF LAND
[I, xi, 1, p. 160]
RENT, considered as the price paid for the use of land, is naturally the
highest which the tenant can afford to pay in the actual circumstances of
the land. In adjusting the terms of the lease, the landlord endeavours to
leave him no greater share of the produce than what is sufficient to keep
up the stock from which he furnishes the seed, pays the labour, and
purchases and maintains the cattle and other instruments of husbandry,
together with the ordinary profits of farming stock in the neighbourhood.
This is evidently the smallest share with which the tenant can content
himself without being a loser, and the landlord seldom means to leave him
any more. . .
The rent of land, it may be thought, is frequently no more than a
reasonable profit or interest for the stock laid out by the landlord upon
its improvement. This, no doubt, may be partly the case upon some
occasions; for it can scarce ever be more than partly the case. The
landlord demands a rent even for unimproved land, and the supposed
interest or profit upon the expense of improvement is generally an
addition to this original rent. Those improvements, besides, are not
always made by the stock of the landlord, but sometimes by that of the
tenant. When the lease comes to be renewed, however, the landlord commonly
demands the same augmentation of rent as if they had been all made by his
own.
[I, xi, 5, p. 161]
The rent of the land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use
of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned
to what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land,
or to what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to
give.
[I, xi, 8, p. 162]
Rent, it is to be observed, therefore, enters into the composition of the
price of commodities in a different way from wages and profit. High or low
wages and profit are the causes of high or low price; high or low rent is
the effect of it. It is because high or low wages and profit must be paid,
in order to bring a particular commodity to market, that its price is high
or low. But it is because its price is high or low; a great deal more, or
very little more, or no more, than what is sufficient to pay those wages
and profit, that it affords a high rent, or a low rent, or no rent at all.
Book 2, Chapter 3
OF THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL, OR OF PRODUCTIVE AND UNPRODUCTIVE LABOUR
[II, iii, 16, p. 337]
Parsimony, and not industry, is the immediate cause of the increase of
capital. Industry, indeed, provides the subject which parsimony
accumulates. But whatever industry might acquire, if parsimony did not
save and store up, the capital would never be the greater.
Parsimony, by
increasing the fund which is destined for the maintenance of productive
hands, tends to increase the number of those hands whose labour adds to
the value of the subject upon which it is bestowed…
What is annually
saved is as regularly consumed as what is annually spent, and nearly in
the same time too; but it is consumed by a different set of people. That
portion of his revenue which a rich man annually spends is in most cases
consumed by idle guests and menial servants, who leave nothing behind them
in return for their consumption. That portion which he annually saves, as
for the sake of the profit it is immediately employed as a capital, is
consumed in the same manner, and nearly in the same time too, but by a
different set of people, by labourers, manufacturers, and artificers, who
reproduce with a profit the value of their annual consumption. His
revenue, we shall suppose, is paid him in money. Had he spent the whole,
the food, clothing, and lodging, which the whole could have purchased,
would have been distributed among the former set of people. By saving a
part of it, as that part is for the sake of the profit immediately
employed as a capital either by himself or by some other person, the food,
clothing, and lodging, which may be purchased with it, are necessarily
reserved for the latter. The consumption is the same, but the consumers
are different.
[II, iii, 27, p. 341]
It can seldom happen, indeed, that the
circumstances of a great nation can be much affected either by the
prodigality or misconduct of individuals; the profusion or imprudence of
some being always more than compensated by the frugality and good conduct
of others.
[II, iii, 28, p. 342]
Though the principle of expense, therefore, prevails in almost all men
upon some occasions, and in some men upon almost all occasions, yet in the
greater part of men, taking the whole course of their life at an average,
the principle of frugality seems not only to predominate, but to
predominate very greatly.
[II, iii, 30, p. 342]
Great nations are never impoverished by private, though they sometimes are
by public prodigality and misconduct. The whole, or almost the whole
public revenue, is in most countries employed in maintaining unproductive
hands. Such are the people who compose a numerous and splendid court, a
great ecclesiastical establishment, great fleets and armies, who in time
of peace produce nothing, and in time of war acquire nothing which can
compensate the expense of maintaining them, even while the war lasts. Such
people, as they themselves produce nothing, are all maintained by the
produce of other men's labour. When multiplied, therefore, to an
unnecessary number, they may in a particular year consume so great a share
of this produce, as not to leave a sufficiency for maintaining the
productive labourers, who should reproduce it next year. . . Those
unproductive hands . . . may consume so great a share of their whole
revenue . . . that all the frugality and good conduct of individuals may
not be able to compensate the waste and degradation of produce occasioned
by this violent and forced encroachment.
[II, iii, 31, p. 342]
This frugality and good conduct, however, is upon most occasions, it
appears from experience, sufficient to compensate, not only the private
prodigality and misconduct of individuals, but the public extravagance of
government. The uniform, constant, and uninterrupted effort of every man
to better his condition, the principle from which public and national, as
well as private opulence is originally derived, is frequently powerful
enough to maintain the natural progress of things towards improvement, in
spite both of the extravagance of government and of the greatest errors of
administration. Like the unknown principle of animal life, it frequently
restores health and vigour to the constitution, in spite, not only of the
disease, but of the absurd prescriptions of the doctor.
|