Capital Controls: Capital Idea or Capital Folly?
Since
the Asian crisis erupted, undermining the legitimacy of the Suharto Government,
Indonesia has been wracked by unrest. In some cities, the authorities responded
with an emergency curfew, prohibiting people from going out at night. Some
observers have gone so far as to suggest that Indonesia would be a safer place
if those measures were maintained indefinitely.
In
neighboring Malaysia, meanwhile, Prime Minister Mahathir Mohamed has imposed a
curfew on capital. Once the home of one of the world’s most highly capitalized
stock markets and open financial markets, Malaysia now controls all purchases
and sales of its currency, the ringget, for purposes related to international
financial transactions. Not just banks and stock brokers are affected: citizens
are prohibited from taking as little as $100 out of the country, and the law is
enforced by random searches at the airport.
Mr.
Mahathir argues that this infringement of the civil liberties of Malaysia’s
citizens, like a dusk-to-dawn curfew, is needed to protect its economy and
society against marauding hedge funds mugging innocent bystanders. It would be
madness, in his view, to leave currency speculators unrestrained, unnecessarily
jeopardizing the health and well-being of the Malaysianeconomy.
This once-radical view has found support in some surprising quarters. Capital controls, long regarded as anathema by respectable economists, are back in fashion. Late this summer, MIT’s Paul Krugman authored a widely-cited article arguing that emergency conditions warranted emergency measures. Warning that the crisis countries of Asia were experiencing a full-scale meltdown, he urged them to consider using controls as shelter behind which to reflate their collapsing economies.
His
statement was viewed, rightly or wrongly, as giving Mr. Mahathir intellectual
cover for his radical initiative. Harvard’s Dani Rodrik, meanwhile, issued a
blanket indictment of capital market liberalization. Rodrik argued that there
is in fact no evidence that countries that free capital flows grow faster,
while it is self-evident that international financial liberalization exposes
them to the danger of debilitating crises.
This
apostasy flies in the face of all that is sacred to economists and has
predictably provoked harsh criticism of those voicing such unconventional
views. The normal presumption in economics is that markets know better than
governments and that, left to their own devices, they allocate resources
reasonably well. Yet the suspicion remains that there is something different
about international financial markets.
The
founding fathers of the Bretton Woods System, Harry Dexter White and John
Maynard Keynes, certainly thought so: the Bretton Woods Agreement negotiated
under their guidance, while encouraging economic liberalization generally,
authorized --indeed, encouraged -- countries to retain restrictions on
international financial transactions. Only
in recent years, responding to pressure from the IMF and the United States,
have governments, first in Europe and Japan and now in various emerging
markets, finally abandoned capital controls. The Asian crisis now suggests, or
so it would appear, that this was a serious mistake.
Not that it is clear why international financial transactions should be treated differently from other transactions, or why the normal presumption that markets know better than bureaucrats is invalid in this case. Is it that the transactions in question are financial, or that they are international? Are capital controls justified as emergency measures in a period of unprecedented crisis, or should they be retained as permanent protection against unreliable financial markets? Should they be considered by all financially-exposed economies or only emerging markets? Unfortunately, the discussion to date has confused these issues more than it has illuminated them.
The Fundamental Case for Financial
Liberalization
The
most basic insight of modern welfare economics is that self-interested economic
actions maximize the collective interest -- or, to put the point more simply,
that markets allocate resources in socially-desirable ways. While they may not
work perfectly, all the evidence, be it from import substitution in Latin
America in the 1950s and 1960s or from central planning in the Soviet Union, is
that they produce better outcomes than heavy-handed bureaucratic control.
There
is no obvious reason why this presumption should apply less to financial than
other markets. Indeed, studies by the World Bank have consistently shown that
countries with more developed financial markets grow faster. Experience with
policies of financial repression in developing countries and with state
monopolies over financial transactions in the Eastern Bloc clearly shows that
stifling financial markets can jeopardize growth.
If
domestic financial markets have clear benefits, it is not clear a priori why
the benefits of international financial markets should be less. International
financial transactions transfer resources from high-saving to low-saving
countries. They allow economies experiencing business-cycle disturbances to
smooth the time profiles of consumption and investment. They allow firms and
households to diversify away country-specific risks.
The presumption in favor of markets being so strong, any counter-argument had better be based on incontrovertible evidence. Rodrik’s evidence is widely cited: using data for a cross-section of countries, he finds no association between capital flows and economic growth, which, he argues, seals the case against capital account liberalization.
This
is what Jeffrey Frankel refers to as fail-safe econometrics: “The secret of
empirical work is to define your hypothesis so that failure to find significant
results can be interpreted as support.” Statisticians can fail to find a
relationship between capital account liberalization and growth not because none
exists but because they have inadvertently omitted from their analysis other
variables that are negatively associated with growth but positively associated
with the decision to open the capital account.
It is plausible that countries that decide to keep their capital accounts
open and closed differ from one another in other ways, including ways for which
the statistician finds difficult to control.
In
a sense, those who argue that today’s developing countries should resist
capital account liberalization are adopting something of a double standard. All
of today’s advanced industrial countries have opened their capital accounts.
All of them have rendered their currencies convertible for capital account
transactions. Doing so is the logical culmination of the process of developing
a deep, mature and efficient domestic financial system.
In
a fundamental sense, domestic and international financial liberalization go
together, since it is hard to liberalize domestic financial transactions and at
the same time keep a lid on cross-border transactions.
Some would argue that
capital account liberalization is also a concomitant of political
liberalization: capital controls necessarily infringe on the economic freedom
of residents and are not a policy of a country in which most readers of this
paper would themselves prefer to live.
There is a valid argument, as we shall see below, that developing countries should control capital flows while they build deep and diversified financial systems, upgrade prudential supervision, and strengthen their monetary and fiscal institutions — in other words, for using them as transitional measures — but not that such countries should permanently pursue different policies toward the capital account than those which became high-income countries before them.
The transition may be a long one, but the comment made by Marx in another context, that the more advanced economy shows the less advanced economy a picture of the latter’s future, is apposite here.
Capital Controls as
Prudential Measures
Markets
may be the best mechanism we have for allocating financial resources, but
history has also shown that they can be dangerously unstable. Like a trapeze
artist, the financial system can perform miraculous tricks but experience a
bone-shattering fall if allowed to perform without a net.
Banks
in particular share the trapeze artist’s vulnerability. Their investments are
less liquid than their deposits; this is what we mean when we say that banks provide
“liquidity-transformation services.” They operate in an imperfect information
environment; one of their basic functions is to develop long-term relationships
with their clients as a way of acquiring proprietary information about their
borrowers’ credit worthiness. But the fact that other financial-market
participants will not have equally good information about those customers means
that banks can raise funds in a crisis only by disposing of assets at fire-sale
prices and doing further damage to their balance sheets. Banks do extensive business with one another;
hence, problems in one create problems in others. For all these reasons, a
sudden loss of depositor confidence can produce a system-wide panic that brings
the entire banking system to its knees.
Securities markets share many of the same vulnerabilities. Investors are prone to quick collective reactions. Being imperfectly informed about market conditions, they tend to infer information about the fundamental value of their investments from one another’s actions. Economists have coined the elegant term “information cascades” to denote this phenomenon, which in practice simply means that investors move in a herd, stampeding in and out of markets.
Moreover,
investors take positions on credit, so that when the market moves against them,
they are required to put up additional collateral. They can thus be forced to
sell into a falling market, amplifying asset price volatility. And a large
price fall can bring bank and nonbank intermediaries down with it, disrupting
the supply of credit to the economy as a whole. The case of Long Term Capital
Management reminds us that this scenario is no mere hypothetical.
These
are all reasons why governments limit the difficulty of the tricks that banks
and other financial-market participants are allowed to attempt. To limit banks’
exposure to market and credit risk, they impose ceilings on concentrated
investments and positions in foreign exchange. They limit the amount of margin
money, or leverage, that equity markets participants are allowed to use. And they do not allow banks to perform
intermediation services without a net. The financial safety net, which takes
the form of deposit insurance and the existence of lender of last resort, is
designed to catch financial-market participants when they fall.
This is where an open and unregulated capital account poses special risks. Banks enjoying government guarantees and seeking to lever up their bets can do so more readily when the capital account is opened. If they borrow in foreign currency, they strip the authorities of their ability to act as lenders of last resort: a central bank can’t print foreign currency, and its capacity to provide commercial banks the foreign exchange they need to make good on their foreign obligations is limited to its stock of international reserves. Even if the liabilities of the banks are denominated in domestic currency, a central bank trying to peg the exchange rate will find itself between a rock and a hard place. It will have to choose between draining liquidity from the markets to defend the exchange rate, or injecting liquidity to defend the banks. It will not be possible to do both.
These
are arguments for using capital controls to backstop other forms of prudential
regulation — as reinforcement for other, more conventional measures to limit
systemic risk and to prevent banks and other intermediaries from taking on
additional risk in response to the provision of the financial safety net.
In
a market economy, prudent risk management is first and foremost the
responsibility of bank owners and managers themselves; since they are the ones
making the investment decisions, they should bear the consequences. This is why banks are required to hold
capital and issue subordinated debt -- so that their owners and important
creditors have something to lose. The second line of defense against excessive
risk taking is the regulators, who monitor and supervise the banks and need to
take prompt corrective action when they see evidence of fraud, incompetence, or
gambling for redemption. But where
risk-management practices are underdeveloped and the regulators lack
administrative capacity and insulation from political pressures, it may be
necessary to build a third line of defense -- to limit excessive risk taking
which threatens systemic stability by limiting the ability of the banks to
borrow abroad. And where limits on bank borrowing can be circumvented by having
corporations do the borrowing and lend the proceeds to the banks, this will mean
controlling or taxing, a la Chile, all capital inflows, whether the borrower of
record is a bank or someone else.
These arguments do not justify any and all regulations that governments might be tempted to impose to prevent their citizens from borrowing abroad. Capital controls can be justified on prudential grounds only if they do not arbitrarily discriminate in favor of some banks and residents over others. They are justifiable only where financial markets are thin, the private sector’s risk-management practices are underdeveloped, and the regulators’ capacity to supervise the financial sector is limited — in other words, where the conventional defenses against systemic risk are not enough. In practice, these last three preconditions, and therefore the argument for capital-inflow taxes or controls, apply to the vast majority of developing countries. For emerging markets, an open capital account should be the exception, not the rule.
Eventually,
financial markets will deepen, bankers will acquire more sophisticated
risk-management skills, and regulators will gain experience, competence and
independence. At that point, restrictions on foreign borrowing should be
removed, and the economy can graduate to the club of high-income countries with
financial systems fully open to international transactions. But here, as in
other forms of financial regulation, it is smart to err in the direction of
caution -- to be absolutely sure that the necessary preconditions are in place
before opening the capital account.
After Mexico in 1994 and Asia in 1997, do we really need a third
reminder of the dangers of premature and precipitous financial liberalization?
Capital Controls as
Emergency Measures
One
country after another, from Thailand to Indonesia, to Korea and now Brazil, has
been forced to respond to the crisis in emerging markets and the resulting
recessionary pressures by cutting its budget deficit, not increasing it as the
textbook Keynesian advice would suggest. The single greatest discovery of the
Keynesian revolution, namely the importance of fiscal stabilizers, has thus
been thrown out the window.
Some would say this simply reflects bad advice by the IMF, which required budget cuts of the Asian crisis countries as a condition for the disbursal of official funds, and which is now demanding the same of Brazil despite forecasts of recession there. In fact, the Fund is merely mirroring market sentiment. Were a country like Brazil to respond to slower economic growth by cutting taxes and increasing public spending, investors would flee, the currency would crash, and the resulting investment collapse and financial distress would only make the recession worse.
Thus, market discipline is perverse. As Krugman puts it, “Brazil, we are informed, must suffer a recession because of its unresolved budget deficit. Huh? Since when does a budget deficit require a recession (which itself will, of course, make the deficit that much harder to bring down).” This is at least part of the rationale for the capital controls imposed by Mr. Mahathir — to provide the leeway to implement a more expansionary fiscal policy and offset an impending recession. It is the realization that has led “otherwise respectable economists” to suggest the use of capital controls to stem capital flight and thereby preserve governments’ freedom to pursue counter cyclical fiscal policies.
Controls
have costs — they require a burdensome administrative bureaucracy, reduce the
pressure for policy reform, and interrupt access to foreign sources of
investment finance — but their benefits may still dominate if they allow the
stabilizing use of macroeconomic policy instruments to be regained.
Whether this is a sensible argument hinges on which of two models of market discipline one believes. If investors are irrational and inclined to panic when the government activates its macroeconomic stabilizers, then it can be sensible for countries to use controls to protect themselves from such irrationality. If, on the other hand, investors respond negatively because they correctly anticipate that it is governments themselves that are prone to respond perversely to the crisis, then the solution is not to use controls to relax market discipline but for the government to clean up its act.
The
argument goes like this. Some governments lack fiscal discipline, and they are
perennially battling the consequences. Like an overweight man, they are
continually trying to teach themselves to stay away from the refrigerator. If
the fat man says “I’ve had a lousy day; I’m going make myself feel better by
having a piece of cake,” his friends are likely to revise downward their
estimates of the likelihood that he will stick to his diet.
Governments
with a history of fiscal laxity that have a lousy macroeconomic day and respond
by increasing their budget deficits similarly run the risk of being
re-evaluated in this way -- of being seen as having reverted to their bad old
habits of running budget deficits and living beyond their means. And if investors
rationally expect budget deficits to be monetized, then deficits today imply
inflation tomorrow, encouraging the rational investor to take the first
opportunity to get his money out of the country.
This
explains the supposedly paradoxical fact that deficit spending in the United
States strengthens the currency while deficit spending in Brazil weakens it. In
the U.S. case, no one expects the Fed to monetize the deficit; hence,
additional government spending pushes up demand, pushes up the real interest rate,
and pushes up the real exchange rate. In the Brazilian case, however,
monetization is a real possibility (pun intended),
implying more inflation and ultimately the need to devalue the currency.
It
is also why the other textbook advice for responding to a recession--devaluing
the currency in order to switch spending toward domestic goods -- can have such
catastrophic effects in emerging markets. Countries weaning themselves from
inflation often do so by pegging the exchange rate, which ties the hands of the
central bank and signals the government that the inflation tax will no longer
be available.
The currency peg is thus the lock on the refrigerator. Countries that devalue are thus seen as having removed the lock from the refrigerator and relapsing to the bad old days of inflationary excess, which leads investors to flee.
The
first-best solution in this case is not to impose capital controls but to
eliminate the problems leading to the excesses in monetary and fiscal policies
in the first place. The most convincing way of signaling that not just current
policies but also future policies will be sound and stable is to reform the
economic and political arrangements by which they are made.
A large literature now shows quite convincingly that better policy-making institutions produce better outcomes. For monetary policy the point is well known: more independent central banks are better able to resist political pressures to monetize budget deficits and generally run lower inflation rates. For fiscal policy, there are parallel arguments for creating an independent national fiscal council constitutionally empowered to set a ceiling for each year’s budget deficit, along with automatic, legally-mandated procedures for what will be done if deficit spending threatens to broach that limit.
Less
ambitiously, fiscal reforms which vest more agenda-setting power in the hands
of the prime minister or finance minister, thereby reining in the common-pool
problem that arises in the presence of autonomous spending ministries (none of
which has an incentive to fully take into account the impact of its additional
spending on the deficit as a whole), have been shown to be associated with
smaller deficits and debts. Similarly, measures that enhance the transparency
of budgeting make it easier for voters to detect politicians who place
self-serving goals above the national interest and hence are likely to produce
better fiscal outcomes.
With
these fundamental institutional reforms in place, markets will not conclude that
monetary expansion tomorrow. The
freedom to use fiscal and monetary policies counter cyclically will be
regained, and capital mobility will no longer be a threat.
Redesigning
monetary and fiscal institutions to deliver better outcomes needn’t take forever.
A simple law — or better, a constitutional amendment — establishing the
independence of the central bank, appointing its governors to long terms in
office, and reining in the fiscal autonomy of the spending ministries and lower
levels of government can be adopted in short order. Time may be required,
however, for the new institutions to establish a track record of delivering
sound and stable macroeconomic policies. Still, Argentina’s example suggests
that this can be accomplished in a matter of years. By adopting such reforms,
Argentina moved from being an inflationary basket case and a capital-market
pariah to one of the few emerging market economies able to float bonds on
international capital markets and avoid excessive macroeconomic tightening in the
global financial turbulence of the second half of 1998.
There
may still be a role for capital controls to loosen the constraints on the use
of counter cyclical monetary and fiscal policies while a country attempts to
get from here to there. But it is reaching the destination that is key.
Conclusion
Developing
countries have special financial problems. Their monetary and fiscal
institutions lack credibility. Their regulators lack administrative capacity.
Their financial markets are shallow. They cannot borrow abroad in domestic
currency. However much one tries to assume away these problems, the fact of the
matter is that these are the defining features of an underdeveloped economy.
And so long as they are present, there are arguments that special deficits
today necessarily mean deficits tomorrow, or that monetary expansion today
means measures, including capital controls, to limit risks to the financial
system and to free up the use monetary and fiscal policies in a slump.
With time, developing countries will develop. Their financial markets will deepen; their macroeconomic and regulatory institutions will grow more robust. With these and other institutional preconditions in place, they will graduate to the club of high-income countries. This will have a important social and economic benefits, not the least of which is that remaining restrictions on international financial transactions can come off. The most critical point of all is therefore that any recourse to capital controls in the meantime should not be taken as an excuse to slow down the fundamental processes of institutional development and policy reform.